Operations Management folk (and those who took MBA classes on operations management) would generally love pull systems. The fact is, a properly implemented pull system that is in harmony with the conduct of retail operations greatly reduces inventory in the supply chain, meaning that less product is just sitting in some warehouse or storeroom. Pull is wonderful for goods that are standard or of limited customization.
However, where retail operations are such that one does not sells "cars" but an assortment of models and makes with various major options. The fact is, each customer comes in with demand for one car and, implicitly, a short list of variations he/she would like/accept in some preference order (and with a range of acceptable prices). This implicit list of acceptable cars can be very short or very long (for the less picky). Now if a customer comes by with a short list of acceptable options and can't find one on the, now sparse, lot, there is a substantial likelihood that the sale would be lost. It would appear that retail operations here behaves like maintenance operations for systems that require a high up-time — the particular spare parts and the particular maintenance specialist must be on hand at the time.
Since in most business transformations, consultants are called in to make concrete recommendations on what to change and how, I blame bad consultants for this mess. Clearly the end-to-end operations were not properly considered in the implementation of the sexy new "lean" paradigm. The fact is, this is not a case where "we didn't expect this to happen" could be responsibly argued.
Before laughing their way to the bank, the consultants could, at the very least, have done some thought experiments on what would happen if a customer came in and happened to not find what he/she wanted. Tracing that to the allocation system would have given some reason to make the system more robust. Moreover, such a scenario would not be of the "Black Swan" variety, necessitating some analysis on this particular "use case" of the "car manufacturing and distribution system". (In fact it would be more like the random variable "Is there a swan in Swan Lake in the time interval [T1, T2]?") Unintended consequences can surely not be argued in this case.
Some time ago, I read The Boston Consulting Group On Strategy (2nd Ed, Wiley, 2006, edited by Stern, C.W. and Deimler, M.) wherein Bruce D. Henderson, the founder of the Boston Consulting Group, (and the man most responsible for the famous BCG 2x2 growth-share matrix) was said to believe that:
- ... while most people understand first-order effects, few deal well with second-and third-order effects. Unfortunately, virtually everything interesting in business lies in fourth-order effects and beyond.
Consider the aftermath of the recent financial crisis of 2007-2009, everything looks perfect on hindsight. But prior to that money gots in the way of "the good ideas winning out". After the damage was done and there was no more money to cloud judgment, everything became clear and we wondered why no one saw things coming.
In Aug 2005, Raghuram Rajan, Chief Economist of the International Monetary Fund from 2003 to 2006, gave a speech about (i) how "competition" "forces" bankers and traders to "flirt continuously with the limits of illiquidity", (ii) how investment managers returns have a huge personal upside for taking on more risk and the downside is trivial, (iii) regulations should be in place to align incentives (this being my summary of his recommendations. As BusinessWeek (Feb 13-Feb 20, 2011) put it, "he was treated like a skunk at the party". It even noted that Lawrence Summers, former US Treasury Secretary and then president of Harvard, said he found "the basic, slightly Luddite premise" of Rajan's presentation to be "largely misguided". What people say is aligned with money. I find it absurd that an economist of Summers' standing could snort so pretentiously at the idea of aligning the behavior of agents to systemic objectives through the appropriate incentives.
Returning to original topic (after that rant of sorts), consultants to business play an important role of filtering academic output and tailoring it to particular business settings. Where they do, the results can be spectacularly good. Where they get lazy and transplant ideas without sufficient adaptation to particulars of an industry, unintended consequences arise. And these unintended consequences can show up after some time has huge negative effects. Laziness often takes the form of assumptions that explain away the need for more analysis (usually on incentives) or work (building institutions that align behavior to systemic objectives). Laziness explained away and still explains away the moral hazard of the financial industry with the now popularly rejected notion that bankers and traders are upright custodians of investors'/savers' money.
Consultants have an important role to play. While much new knowledge comes from academia, it is often general and abstract. Solutions arising from academia often take the form "if operations are structured like A and B holds, then C happens". Where the conditions of B are at variance with reality, it should be studied whether the outcome deviates significantly from the desired C. The value of consultants is their wider exposure to industry. Their recommendations should be made in the context of actual, real world, operations.
No comments:
Post a Comment